Bitcoin Not the Final Word
By George Selgin
Unless you know what terms like “blockchain” and “public ledger” mean, you will find the many aspects of bitcoin hard to fathom. But one thing that’s straightforward is the rule governing the total quantity of bitcoin in existence.
According to that rule, the number of bitcoins in circulation, now just shy of 14.2 million, will grow at an ever-diminishing rate as it approaches its ultimate limit of 21 million coins. By 2030, new coin output will be reduced to a mere trickle. By 2050, it will have practically ceased.
To suggest that bitcoin is doomed for any reason at all, let alone for some specific reason, is to go way out on a flimsy limb. So I hope I’ll be forgiven for saying that the fixed long-run quantity of bitcoin will doom it only in one particular but important respect: namely, by ruling out the possibility of it becoming a more stable exchange medium, let alone a more popular one, than the US dollar.
Don’t get me wrong: I’m not particularly crazy about the dollar. In fact, I think it’s a lousy currency, except when compared to most other government-supplied currencies, which are even worse. (If you want to see a really crazy money supply “protocol,” just have a look at how the supply of dollars has evolved since the Federal Reserve took charge of it in 1914).
Nevertheless, the dollar has at least one tremendous advantage over bitcoin, which is its huge and well-established network of users. The dollar’s big head start means that if any new currency is going to challenge it, it has to be not just a little better, but far better.
In at least one way bitcoins are better than dollars: they can be transferred at practically no cost, and with a degree of anonymity unmatched by any other sort of electronic money. But for a currency to make big inroads against an established, official money, it has to offer the further advantage of a stable and predictable purchasing power.
Next to its large network of users, the relative stability of the dollar’s purchasing power has been the main reason for its popularity abroad, both officially (in “dollarized” economies like Panama and Ecuador) and unofficially. Although dollars tend to depreciate, they do so less rapidly than many other currencies.
With bitcoin’s ultimately fixed supply, the long-run risk is the danger, not of depreciation, but of unpredictable and excessively rapid depreciation. As economies grow, so does their real demand for money. Consequently, either the quantity of money units must keep up, or prices must decline to make existing units worth more.
Mild deflation may not be a problem. But if the demand for money grows rapidly, it might not prove possible to reduce prices — and especially wages — rapidly enough to keep up with it without encountering serious resistance. Even under the gold standard the supply of money tended to keep up with demand, especially in the long run, as gold output responded to falling prices (which meant a higher relative price of gold).
A fixed-quantity monetary standard, on the other hand, isn’t likely to prove consistent with either short- or long-run price level stability. Indeed, and perhaps paradoxically, the more popular bitcoin becomes, the more likely it is to appreciate rapidly, and the less attractive it will seem as a primary means of exchange, meaning one in which contracts are written and accounts are kept.
To say this isn’t, I hasten to add, to suggest that bitcoin can play no important part in our monetary future. First of all, it may long continue to play a part, and perhaps an increasingly important one, as a secondary or “parallel” one, without ever displacing dollars as primary or “standard” money. As a means of making foreign remittances, for example, its superiority is already well established. More importantly, though bitcoin is thus far the most successful cryptocurrency, it is hardly the last word.
The ingenious technology behind it is fully capable of being modified, and of otherwise pointing the way toward alternatives that may prove superior, not only to bitcoin, but to any bureaucratically managed money.
George Selgin is a senior fellow and director of the Center for Monetary and Financial Alternatives at the Cato Institute. He is the author of several books, including Less Than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy (The Institute of Economic Affairs, 1997), and most recently, Good Money: Birmingham Button Makers, the Royal Mint, and the Beginnings of Modern Coinage (University of Michigan Press, 2008). Follow @tonidepoli.
Inflation Resistance Boosts Bitcoin
By Konrad S. Graf
EspañolFirst, the total supply of bitcoin is not fixed. It will continue rising for more than a century. The rate of growth, however, is pre-charted, and declines steadily toward zero around 2140.
The total amount of useable bitcoin can also be reduced, mostly by tiny amounts in the scheme of things, because individual users can permanently lose access to some bitcoin, mostly by forgetting passwords and not having backups.
That said, bitcoin is free from upward quantitative manipulation, or “inflation” in the more traditional sense of that word. Far from being a source of bitcoin’s potential downfall, however, inflation resistance is one of its most innovative and attractive monetary features.
New bitcoin creation in the growth phase doubles as an incentive for bitcoin miners — beyond transaction-fee revenue — to operate and strengthen the peer-to-peer network during its formative stages when it is most vulnerable and the transaction-fee market least developed. Miners earn new coins in exchange for mission-critical services of transaction processing and enhancing overall network security.
In contrast, when new units of a money are produced arbitrarily by means only of political power and special legal privileges, this transfers wealth — unearned — toward the first recipients of these new units and away from the general population of other existing money holders. Such inflation transfers are a sub-zero-sum game that benefits special interests at a greater total expense to others.
The process can persist partly because it is subtle and few understand it. As negative and pervasive as these effects are, devaluing money by increasing the number of units is widely considered good and absolutely necessary. How could this be so?
One simple aspect, among many others, may be a flat-Earth type of intuition, by which I mean something that seems to make perfect sense even though it is completely wrong. In everyday experience, each individual and organization tends to dream of having “more money.”
This is naturally equated to having more wealth. It is not much of a stretch from there to imagine that if there were only more money available in society as a whole, then the general welfare would improve. Everyone would be better off with “more money.”
But such an intuitive association with individual cases does not translate at all. In the unique case of money, as contrasted with other goods and services, any given total quantity when viewed across a society of users can fill the same roles as any other such quantity, provided there is sufficient divisibility — an issue only of historical interest.
Chief among these purposes is facilitating the activities of saving, trading, investing, and lending.
If bitcoin were to meet a downfall, or at least stumble, I suspect it would more likely be from something to do with networking or cryptography. Its economics are quite sound, in my view, remarkably so in the context of the theory and history of money.
Konrad S. Graf writes on bitcoin, monetary theory, legal theory, and some other topics at his website. Follow @KonradSGraf.